JessicaGuzikFirstPaper 2 - 28 Apr 2012 - Main.EbenMoglen
|
|
META TOPICPARENT | name="FirstPaper" |
| |
< < | It is strongly recommended that you include your outline in the body of your essay by using the outline as section titles. The headings below are there to remind you how section and subsection titles are formatted. | | The Price of Facebook
-- By JessicaGuzik - 12 Mar 2012 | | Introduction | |
< < | The dangers of Facebook’s ability to track our personal data continues to become more apparent, yet most users continue to use this and similar on-line services despite their implications regarding the loss of our privacy. For me, this raises a major question that I want to explore: why do consumers of Facebook so readily relinquish their personal information in exchange for this, and similar, social networking services? I hypothesize that my generation is so accustomed to the conveniences and benefits that we believe we are getting from these types of services, that we overvalue the harm that would result from our choosing to disconnect from these services. This dissuades us from unplugging even in the face of violations of our privacy. I therefore want to explore other potential arguments to persuade a non-privacy-conscious generation that the use of these services is not in our interests as consumers. In this paper, I focus on the opportunity cost of relinquishing our personal information to a third party for free. I argue that we are giving third parties valuable information, and we should therefore at least question whether access to their social networking services is adequate compensation for the handing over of this information. | > > | The dangers of Facebook’s ability to track our personal data continues to become more apparent, yet most users continue to use this and similar on-line services despite their implications regarding the loss of our privacy. For me, this raises a major question that I want to explore: why do consumers of Facebook so readily relinquish their personal information in exchange for this, and similar, social networking services? | | | |
> > |
These two blowsy sentences could be one compact question: "Why,
despite the evident dangers, do users of Facebook and similar
services give away their personal data to social network operators?"
That would save fifty words for other purposes and improve the
introduction. You still need to strive for economy.
I hypothesize that my generation is so accustomed to the conveniences and benefits that we believe we are getting from these types of services, that we overvalue the harm that would result from our choosing to disconnect from these services. This dissuades us from unplugging even in the face of violations of our privacy. I therefore want to explore other potential arguments to persuade a non-privacy-conscious generation that the use of these services is not in our interests as consumers. In this paper, I focus on the opportunity cost of relinquishing our personal information to a third party for free. I argue that we are giving third parties valuable information, and we should therefore at least question whether access to their social networking services is adequate compensation for the handing over of this information.
But you've already said that the conveniences and benefits are
important. And your question assumes that there are necessary
trade-offs between social networking services and privacy protection.
The situation is graver if that's true, But you present no evidence,
and I don't think it is. So I'm left wondering how far your analysis
can help.
| | The Challenges | | I hypothesize that my generation in particular has a hard time grasping the concept of privacy, because most of us are not familiar with a time in our adult lives when social media did not play a role in our social interactions. We are less hesitant to relinquish information via the internet because we have a lessened awareness of the fact that we are “sharing” this information with anyone besides our acquaintances. We have been deprived of the opportunity to experience a life in which our personal activity was restricted to the physical realms in which we experienced it. Privacy has a different meaning to us than it does to the generation that precedes us. | |
> > | Maybe. But this is only
hypothesis; one might expect you to offer something in its support.
I'm not sure it's true; I think "the preceding generation" would have
behaved the same way under the same stimuli. | | More Problems: the Difficulty of Unplugging | |
< < | This problem is exacerbated by the fact that we find it difficult to imagine living our day-to-day lives without sharing our information with third parties and having access to the information of others as a result. As Mark Zuckerberg was quick to recognize, there was a type of social craving that couldn’t be satiated in the absence of a service like Facebook. Our desire to share our own information while simultaneously being able to access the information of others is a powerful one, and our use of Facebook to satiate this borders on addiction. Even for those who want to unplug, these third parties do not make it easy. The process of removing oneself from Facebook went from being very simple back when the website was first created, to being complicated enough to confuse a significant number of Facebook users. Whether we desire it our not, getting our virtual selves out of this realm of cyberspace is not a straightforward matter. | > > | This problem is exacerbated by the fact that we find it difficult to imagine living our day-to-day lives without sharing our information with third parties and having access to the information of others as a result. As Mark Zuckerberg was quick to recognize, there was a type of social craving that couldn’t be satiated in the absence of a service like Facebook.
Sure it can. The desire for social networking is not
indistinguishable from the desire for social networking that spies on
its users. Facebook's "man-in-the-middle" attack on the Web is not
functionally necessary to have sharing with our friends and
acquaintances, or even with friends of friends. The "give everything
to me and I'll manage it for you," centralized version of the service
is like having the World Wide Web with one server. It isn't
necessary, it's just bad. So we're not required to choose between
having social networking and not being spied on. As I explained more
than once in class, we're also not required to "lose our friends" in
order to fix the problem. Social networking done right could begin
by giving us a transition in which we don't have to stop sharing with
people who use FB, Flickr, etc. Over time, we can transition
together, as a whole, softly, from bad sharing to secure sharing.
That was the idea behind the project called Diaspora, whose authors
tried to implement my ideas on the subject, along with many other
"federated social networking" projects, one or more of which will
eventually succeed and swallow up Facebook, safely.
Our desire to share our own information while simultaneously being able to access the information of others is a powerful one, and our use of Facebook to satiate this borders on addiction. Even for those who want to unplug, these third parties do not make it easy. The process of removing oneself from Facebook went from being very simple back when the website was first created, to being complicated enough to confuse a significant number of Facebook users. Whether we desire it our not, getting our virtual selves out of this realm of cyberspace is not a straightforward matter.
Perhaps not
individually. But collectively it's simpler than it looks to you.
How it looks to you should be closer than it is to how it is, because
I tried to teach you, but did not succeed, evidently, as well as I had hoped.
| | The Economic Value of Our Internet Presence
If our understanding of privacy is incomplete or if we overvalue the cost of dissociating ourselves from the social media sphere of cyberspace, then the loss of privacy argument seems moot to us. For a generation accustomed to instant gratification and convenience at the click of the mouse, the dangers of relinquishing our privacy are difficult arguments to sell to us. For the purpose of persuasion, it may be valuable to explore a different approach for evaluating the price we pay to use Facebook.
This begins with undoing the false notion that Facebook is “free.” Facebook is only free in the most obvious sense of the word, and this is because the company chooses not to charge users money to access the service. Without users’ activity on the site, there is no way to generate revenue other than to charge users to create an account. It is our personal information that lies at the base of the website’s profitability. And in exchange, we get free use of the service. We are essentially purchasing access to this service using our personal data as currency. | |
< < | Given the multiplier effect that occurs when these services gather enough data to fill in the information gaps that exist, the economic value of our on-line activity is significant, and goes beyond the face value of the information that we choose to hand over. This aggregation effect seems to dampen the effects diminishing marginal returns that one might ordinarily expect. This makes sense given that information is not subject to diminishing marginal returns in the same way that other commodities are. With Facebook’s valuation approaching $100 billion, it is difficult to imagine that the economic value of our activity and information is insignificant. If we could avoid the middle-man and sell our own information straight to third parties, how much money might it command on the open market? Because we’re allowing websites like Facebook to step in and conduct the transaction for us, we should question whether we are giving Facebook an excessive commission. Is free access to a social networking service adequate compensation for forgoing participation in a market that allows consumers to extract economic value through strategic disclosure (or non-disclosure) of their information? | > > | Given the multiplier effect that occurs when these services gather enough data to fill in the information gaps that exist, the economic value of our on-line activity is significant, and goes beyond the face value of the information that we choose to hand over. This aggregation effect seems to dampen the effects diminishing marginal returns that one might ordinarily expect. This makes sense given that information is not subject to diminishing marginal returns in the same way that other commodities are. With Facebook’s valuation approaching $100 billion, it is difficult to imagine that the economic value of our activity and information is insignificant.
And yet, as I pointed
out in the course of the term, FB's initial public offering documents
show that it makes a paltry $4.40/year per active user, which
suggests that the returns available on your "Internet presence" by
legitimate means are extremely small, and the costs of providing
alternative services that don't depend on spying are not very
great.
If we could avoid the middle-man and sell our own information straight to third parties, how much money might it command on the open market? Because we’re allowing websites like Facebook to step in and conduct the transaction for us, we should question whether we are giving Facebook an excessive commission. Is free access to a social networking service adequate compensation for forgoing participation in a market that allows consumers to extract economic value through strategic disclosure (or non-disclosure) of their information? | | This raises the possibility that tools like the freedom box could be used to protect more than our privacy – perhaps the ability to control who receives our personal information and how they receive it may allow us to protect the economic value of our personal information. I recognize that such an approach may run counter to the goal of protecting our privacy in many ways, and may introduce an entirely new set of social and political ills. But as I continually observe the difficulty of getting Generation Y concerned about the privacy issues that we face, I seek out a solution that may appeal to a population that has a hard time appreciating the importance and meaning of privacy. | | http://glennstok.hubpages.com/hub/Obsolete-Facebook-Profile-Charade
http://dealbook.nytimes.com/2012/02/01/tracking-facebooks-valuation/ | |
< < |
You are entitled to restrict access to your paper if you want to. But we all derive immense benefit from reading one another's work, and I hope you won't feel the need unless the subject matter is personal and its disclosure would be harmful or undesirable.
To restrict access to your paper simply delete the "#" character on the next two lines:
| > > | These should have been
links in the text. They are not a particularly impressive set of
sources, as I'm sure you can see. Since when is citing TV journalism
the conduct of research?
My concern about this draft is that it seems to depend on factual
assumptions which, though they could be true, are not supported, and
are contrary to other factual propositions I put forward, and
defended, in class. I can be wrong, of course, but I would be more
persuaded if I saw some actual engagement with the ideas I presented.
Two points are central here, both of which I doubt: (1) FB's form of
social networking is necessary if we ar to have social networking at
all, or to avoid having to go "cold turkey" in withdrawal from our
existing ties; and (2) there is much legitimate money to be made on
the on-line activity of social sharing, by ad-brokerage or other
"acceptable" uses of the spying. FB shows the enormous disproportion
between the real money made by ad brokerage and the value attributed
to operation of the database: the difference is the value of the
illegitimate or dodgy uses foreseen, and the implicit value of the
relationships with intelligence and security services around the
world. I don't see how its actual operating results demonstrate a
great untapped economic value in peoples' private lives that would
justify advising them to sell themselves out. The Devil has never
really given high prices for souls; he's waited until low prices
seemed high. I'd be happier about this draft if I thought it was
based on the knowledge necessary to help people see the difference. | | | |
< < | Note: TWiki has strict formatting rules for preference declarations. Make sure you preserve the three spaces, asterisk, and extra space at the beginning of these lines. If you wish to give access to any other users simply add them to the comma separated ALLOWTOPICVIEW list. | > > | | | \ No newline at end of file |
|
JessicaGuzikFirstPaper 1 - 12 Mar 2012 - Main.JessicaGuzik
|
|
> > |
META TOPICPARENT | name="FirstPaper" |
It is strongly recommended that you include your outline in the body of your essay by using the outline as section titles. The headings below are there to remind you how section and subsection titles are formatted.
The Price of Facebook
-- By JessicaGuzik - 12 Mar 2012
Introduction
The dangers of Facebook’s ability to track our personal data continues to become more apparent, yet most users continue to use this and similar on-line services despite their implications regarding the loss of our privacy. For me, this raises a major question that I want to explore: why do consumers of Facebook so readily relinquish their personal information in exchange for this, and similar, social networking services? I hypothesize that my generation is so accustomed to the conveniences and benefits that we believe we are getting from these types of services, that we overvalue the harm that would result from our choosing to disconnect from these services. This dissuades us from unplugging even in the face of violations of our privacy. I therefore want to explore other potential arguments to persuade a non-privacy-conscious generation that the use of these services is not in our interests as consumers. In this paper, I focus on the opportunity cost of relinquishing our personal information to a third party for free. I argue that we are giving third parties valuable information, and we should therefore at least question whether access to their social networking services is adequate compensation for the handing over of this information.
The Challenges
Generation Y’s Misconception of Privacy
I hypothesize that my generation in particular has a hard time grasping the concept of privacy, because most of us are not familiar with a time in our adult lives when social media did not play a role in our social interactions. We are less hesitant to relinquish information via the internet because we have a lessened awareness of the fact that we are “sharing” this information with anyone besides our acquaintances. We have been deprived of the opportunity to experience a life in which our personal activity was restricted to the physical realms in which we experienced it. Privacy has a different meaning to us than it does to the generation that precedes us.
More Problems: the Difficulty of Unplugging
This problem is exacerbated by the fact that we find it difficult to imagine living our day-to-day lives without sharing our information with third parties and having access to the information of others as a result. As Mark Zuckerberg was quick to recognize, there was a type of social craving that couldn’t be satiated in the absence of a service like Facebook. Our desire to share our own information while simultaneously being able to access the information of others is a powerful one, and our use of Facebook to satiate this borders on addiction. Even for those who want to unplug, these third parties do not make it easy. The process of removing oneself from Facebook went from being very simple back when the website was first created, to being complicated enough to confuse a significant number of Facebook users. Whether we desire it our not, getting our virtual selves out of this realm of cyberspace is not a straightforward matter.
The Economic Value of Our Internet Presence
If our understanding of privacy is incomplete or if we overvalue the cost of dissociating ourselves from the social media sphere of cyberspace, then the loss of privacy argument seems moot to us. For a generation accustomed to instant gratification and convenience at the click of the mouse, the dangers of relinquishing our privacy are difficult arguments to sell to us. For the purpose of persuasion, it may be valuable to explore a different approach for evaluating the price we pay to use Facebook.
This begins with undoing the false notion that Facebook is “free.” Facebook is only free in the most obvious sense of the word, and this is because the company chooses not to charge users money to access the service. Without users’ activity on the site, there is no way to generate revenue other than to charge users to create an account. It is our personal information that lies at the base of the website’s profitability. And in exchange, we get free use of the service. We are essentially purchasing access to this service using our personal data as currency.
Given the multiplier effect that occurs when these services gather enough data to fill in the information gaps that exist, the economic value of our on-line activity is significant, and goes beyond the face value of the information that we choose to hand over. This aggregation effect seems to dampen the effects diminishing marginal returns that one might ordinarily expect. This makes sense given that information is not subject to diminishing marginal returns in the same way that other commodities are. With Facebook’s valuation approaching $100 billion, it is difficult to imagine that the economic value of our activity and information is insignificant. If we could avoid the middle-man and sell our own information straight to third parties, how much money might it command on the open market? Because we’re allowing websites like Facebook to step in and conduct the transaction for us, we should question whether we are giving Facebook an excessive commission. Is free access to a social networking service adequate compensation for forgoing participation in a market that allows consumers to extract economic value through strategic disclosure (or non-disclosure) of their information?
This raises the possibility that tools like the freedom box could be used to protect more than our privacy – perhaps the ability to control who receives our personal information and how they receive it may allow us to protect the economic value of our personal information. I recognize that such an approach may run counter to the goal of protecting our privacy in many ways, and may introduce an entirely new set of social and political ills. But as I continually observe the difficulty of getting Generation Y concerned about the privacy issues that we face, I seek out a solution that may appeal to a population that has a hard time appreciating the importance and meaning of privacy.
http://www.forbes.com/sites/chunkamui/2011/08/08/facebooks-privacy-issues-are-even-deeper-than-we-knew/2/
http://www2.scnow.com/news/2012/mar/04/column-will-endless-connectivity-drive-us-unplug-ar-3338403/
http://articles.cnn.com/2009-04-23/health/ep.facebook.addict_1_facebook-page-facebook-world-social-networking?_s=PM:HEALTH
http://glennstok.hubpages.com/hub/Obsolete-Facebook-Profile-Charade
http://dealbook.nytimes.com/2012/02/01/tracking-facebooks-valuation/
You are entitled to restrict access to your paper if you want to. But we all derive immense benefit from reading one another's work, and I hope you won't feel the need unless the subject matter is personal and its disclosure would be harmful or undesirable.
To restrict access to your paper simply delete the "#" character on the next two lines:
Note: TWiki has strict formatting rules for preference declarations. Make sure you preserve the three spaces, asterisk, and extra space at the beginning of these lines. If you wish to give access to any other users simply add them to the comma separated ALLOWTOPICVIEW list. |
|
|
|
This site is powered by the TWiki collaboration platform. All material on this collaboration platform is the property of the contributing authors. All material marked as authored by Eben Moglen is available under the license terms CC-BY-SA version 4.
|
|